Court Methods & Objectives

The courts in many countries, including UK and USA, are based on the adversarial system, where each side deploys its evidence to best advantage while a neutral judge and jury weight up the evidence presented to reach a decision (the judge rules on whether any particular item of evidence is legally acceptable). Neither judge nor jury has any power to ask questions or carry out any kind of investigation themselves, but must rely entirely on the evidence presented by the opposing sides.

In other countries, such as France, the inquisitorial system is used, under which the judge carries out his own investigation with the object of determining what is the truth of the matter.

Both systems are open to prejudice by judge and, when used, jury. Research carried out quite a long time ago (sorry, I cannot at the moment remember the details – I think it was in a book I read long ago and still have somewhere so I’ll look it up) shows quite clearly that the belief by many people that they can tell when people are lying is simply a delusion. The supposed symptoms of lying are much more commonly the result of shyness, embarrassment or simply pressure from a persistent hostile barrister, trying to exploit just such a weakness to create a false impression of dishonesty on the part of the witness. Prejudice also often arises from a person’s appearance, either their dress or all too often simply their features.

It seems to me obvious that the purpose of the court should be to uncover the truth so as to deliver real justice, but a judge carrying out his own investigations prior to the trial brings with it a much enhanced probability of prejudice. I therefore think a sort of hybrid of the two systems should be used.

The judge and, especially, the jury should have the right to ask their own questions and even to call additional witnesses (but with the judge continuing to rule on the acceptability of the questions), so that the purpose of revealing the truth supersedes the simple contest between two lawyers. To prevent prejudice completely, all evidence should be in writing (probably on computer screens), with neither the judge nor the jury seeing any witness, plaintiff, defendant or lawyer until after the verdict has been declared. The trial would therefore in many ways resemble an on-line chat system.

Serious threat to our democracy

Further to my previous post, a vote to leave the EU, based on the hope that this will enable us to control our borders and stop immigration from eastern Europe, will have disastrous consequences for our democracy.

People who voted to leave for that reason will be disappointed and will feel let down (again) by politicians who will be unable to keep their promises. This will almost certainly lead to a rise in right-wing extremism and a real threat to our democratic system.

EU Membership and Immigration

Why are the Remain Campaign not making a major issue of the Brexiters most effective but false argument – control of immigration?

The main reason the Brexit campaign is making progress is because they are convincing people that leaving the EU would give us control of our borders and allow us to exclude east European immigrants. It will do no such thing.

Even Brexiters admit that if we leave the EU our economic survival will continue to depend on access to the European free market. That means we will have to join the European Economic Area, just like Norway and Switzerland. A condition of that membership is acceptance of EU rules on migration (and some other things). The result would be that we would have less control, not more, over immigration policy. Instead of being one of the biggest EU countries making any changes to the rules, we would be outsiders, bound by rules in which we have no say at all.

TTIP Update

Since I wrote the piece below various things have changed (for the better).

First, some of the various party views have changed, mainly, it seems, as some of the details have become better known, especially the secret courts by which corporations could sue governments over policies which hit their profits.

Second, some European governments (notably but not only France) have declared their opposition to the proposals, so there is a good chance it will all be cancelled.

Third, it has become clear that if we leave the EU our present UK government are quite likely to conclude a similar deal with USA, so leaving the EU would not solve the problem and might well make it worse.

TTIP must be killed!

This treaty is being negotiated in secret between the EU and USA and amounts to a complete corporate takeover and an end to effective democracy. This link is the best explanation of the problems with it that I have found so far:

http://ttip2014.eu/blog-detail/blog/id-30-reasons-why-greens-oppose-ttip.html

I note that 38 Degrees have also started a campaign against it. See: https://secure.38degrees.org.uk/ttip-leaflet-action.

Of the UK political parties, this promised disaster is supported by Labour, Tories, LibDems and UKIP, and opposed only by the Green Party and the Scottish and Welsh nationalists. Mussolini would have loved it.

While I would be reluctant to see us leave the EU (although it needs a lot of reform), if this goes ahead I would regard it as sufficient reason in itself to do so.

Problems with a Sustainable Economy

The traditional economic system progresses in a series of repeating cycles. In times of major unemployment, any increase in income for the majority of people results in an increase in demand for consumer goods. The sale of these gives income to others which again is spent on consumer goods and services. This cyclic effect results in more people being employed, boosting the effect still further.

Once a certain level of demand is reached there is a need to increase productive capacity, not only by increased employment of labour but also by purchase of production equipment, boosting the cycle still further. This process of increasing production, sales, consumption and investment continues until unemployment reaches a low level, at which point the increase must stop. The stop comes because of physical limits, However, because there are delays in the system, demand for goods and services continues to increase, leading to increase in prices (normal supply and demand effect), so a period of inflation ensues.

Since there is no labour available to increase production further, the demand for capital goods begins to fall off, so the whole cycle goes into reverse. This is how capitalist economies have been operating for many decades or even centuries, with governments attempting to intervene with varying degrees of understanding and success.

When a truly sustainable economy is practised, with a stable population level and working to provide sufficient of everything rather than trying to maximise production and consumption, this process cannot function, so what will happen instead?

With population and consumption held at a steady level, there will be little demand for new equipment and even less for the machinery that makes the capital equipment itself – so little that both the machinery itself and the people who know how to use it will only have at best part-time employment in many cases. For example, if everyone who needs a washing machine already has one and the number needed does not change, very few will be needed to replace those completely worn out or damaged, so there is a real danger that the skills needed to make a washing machine may be lost. The equipment and skills needed to make a washing machine are no doubt also used to make other things, but the same problem is likely to apply to them all. I don’t know what the process is for making a modern washing machine, but I have no doubt that they are now mass-produced by automated machinery. In a sustainable economy washing machines, like most things, will be built to last and to be easily repairable, unlike those made today, so far fewer will be needed as replacements

The main problem, however, is that the economic system is inherently unstable, with positive feedback amplifying any perturbation. A means of stabilising it is needed which provides employment for all who want it and a stable currency. No one has yet devised a system for achieving this without abandoning capitalism entirely, and with it the freedom of choice that a satisfactory life demands. There is no doubt that an economy based on sufficiency, instead of greed for ever more wealth, is one essential component of such a solution, but this requires a major shift in society’s values to achieve. In the meantime, and on the way to achieving it, we need to find another means of stabilising the system. Since the problem is not one of negative feedback with lags but the relatively simple one of straightforward positive feedback, the obvious answer is to institute some form of negative feedback. This is what the Keynesian system of stimulating growth in times of high unemployment was designed to do. Unfortunately, at least as it has been applied in the past, it has been excessive, and usually also late, and so has produced not stability but a reversal of the cycle. Something much more finely tuned and promptly applied is needed, and it needs to be applicable in both directions as needed, not just one.

The Keynesian system at least gives us a clue as to what to look for in such a system. The level of unemployment, properly and accurately measured, is what must be measured (or at least one of the things – there may well be others also having an influence), and government expenditure is a major controlling variable, but of course, as always, life is not that simple. One problem is that the effect of government expenditure in this respect depends on what kind of expenditure it is. Money spent on, for example the so-called “quantitative easing” used in the period 2008-2013, which amounted to feeding money to banks in the hope they would in turn lend it to industry to fund expansion, predictably failed, partly because banks chose not to use it in that way and partly because it did nothing to stimulate demand, which alone would encourage industry to want to invest. To be effective, the government expenditure must directly put money into the hands of people who will spend it on goods and services. This can be quite effectively done by spending or reducing spend on infrastructure projects (in accounting terms, capital expenditure) such as transport facilities and energy production, as advocated by Keynes, or it could be done by simply increasing or decreasing welfare benefits (or other revenue expenditure) or by reducing or increasing taxation (not strictly speaking expenditure of course, but its equivalent so far as its effect on this system is concerned). These all have their advantages and disadvantages, both from the point of view of effectiveness and in terms of their other effects on people’s lives and on the overall objective of sustainability.

Before considering those three options, we must also look at other problems with attempting to control the system in this way. When people receive additional income, then do not necessarily spend it all on goods and services, but instead put some of it into savings. Only that part which they spend is effective in stimulating the economy. Economists talk of the “propensity to save”, being the proportion of their additional income that people put into savings instead of spending immediately. It is an established fact of life, and intuitively fairly obvious, that the greater a person’s income the higher their propensity to save is likely to be. At the extreme, a small increase in income to a multi-millionaire would not have any effect whatever on his spending and his propensity to save will be 1 (the maximum – he saves it all because he has nothing extra to spend it on), while the same increase to a person struggling to feed and clothe a family will all be spent immediately on the essentials of living – his propensity to save is zero.

A further problem which is difficult to solve is that when the money is spent on consumer goods and services it may go on things which do little to stimulate employment, such as gambling, or on imported goods. The latter will stimulate the economy of the exporting country, but not that of the country spending the money. The first problem could theoretically be solved by criminalising much of the undesirable activities, but this is hardly compatible with a culture of freedom. The second could be solved, as it was from the time when the gold standard was abandoned in favour of “fixed” exchange rates until the advent of freely floating currencies and the removal of restrictions on the export of money some decades later. This is not the place to discuss the advantages and disadvantages of fixed exchange rates but clearly restrictions on the export of money is again not compatible with freedom.

Now let us look in turn at the main forms of government income and expenditure and consider the implications of each, both in terms of effectiveness and of the wider considerations.

1. Infrastructure projects
Infrastructure projects, if managed properly from this point of view, have been shown many times to be reasonably effective. Not all of the money spent goes to people who will spend it on goods and services, but most of it does (the remainder goes into company reserves and in repayment to banks of company loans and interest on those loans), but there are major delays with some of it when the initial contractor uses some of the funds to buy goods and services from other companies, and even more so with that part which is used to pay dividends to shareholders. Indeed, much of the dividends part goes entirely into savings when the shareholder in an insurance company, pension provider or other financial institution. Most of the money, however, goes directly to people in the form of wages, salaries and directly as payments for goods and services, although not only or even mainly to people who will spend it all.

Most of what we normally think of as infrastructure projects, such as building roads, railways, bridges, power stations, etc. are simply not required in a sustainable, steady-state economy. In a growth economy they are highly desirable and have traditionally been welcomed for this reason, but in a steady state they are only needed as occasional replacements. The equivalent in the form of maintenance of existing facilities could be used instead, although there would be an upper limit to what is needed and a lower limit below which it would be short-sighted to go. This could possibly be at least a part of the control action which should be used, but those limits may not be far apart so its usefulness is very limited.

2. Revenue expenditure

Government revenue expenditure takes many different forms and these need to be considered separately

 

2.1 Direct employment

Many government services are performed by people directly employed by the government. Obvious examples are the armed services, the police, teachers in state schools and health workers in state hospitals and other state health services, but there are many others, the details of which vary somewhat from country to country. The effectiveness of changing this form of expenditure as a control mechanism will depend primarily on the rates on pay of the people concerned. Increasing or reducing the numbers of people employed is not something that can be done instantly, but is likely to take a number of months. However, pay increases can be implemented very quickly, but are much more difficult, both politically and morally, to reduce other than through changes in the number of overtime working hours. It follows that as a rapid two-way mechanism this is only useful to the extent that paid overtime is relevant to the particular jobs, which is much more in some forms of work than in others. Changing the numbers employed, especially in the lower paid jobs, would also be effective if the lower speed of action is compatible with the needs of the system.

 

2.2 Purchase of goods and services

Governments purchase from commercial companies huge quantities of goods and services. The nature of some of these is such that the quantity purchased cannot readily be varies, but many others can be changed very easily, and in that sense are very suitable for our purpose here. However, as usual, life is not so simple. If the result is to put money into the economy, then it must go to individuals who will spend it, not into large company profits nor, as a result of imports, to foreign organisations. On the other hand, if the volume of purchases from very small companies varies too much, the companies themselves will suffer severely when purchases are reduced – this is not necessarily undesirable, since it would involve a direct change to the unemployment level, which is the object of the exercise. Great care must therefore be exercised in choosing which products and services to use for this control purpose. Broad brush budgetary variations at the level of entire government departments is definitely not the way to do it! However, subject to this, we have here a very suitable control.

 

2.3 Welfare payments

Welfare payments are the direct payment of cash to individuals, primarily for the relief of actual or threatened poverty, such as pensions, unemployment relief, disability relief, etc. Properly directed welfare payments, by their very nature, go to those at the bottom of the income scale who will spend more or less all that they receive, so the effect of changes to these will be immediate and total. From the point of view of the control system, they are the ideal tool. From a humanitarian viewpoint, however, they are not suitable at all. The problem is not when an increased economic stimulus, requiring an increase in payments, is needed, but when it is necessary to go in the other direction. Cutting payments to vulnerable people struggling to manage on very limited means is unacceptably cruel. This is a control which could only be acceptable to operate in one direction, which has obvious problems of its own. My conclusion is that this may be useable on occasions, but only for increases and therefore not as a regular part of the system for normal use.

 

3. Tax changes

Since the purpose of taxation is to balance government income and expenditure, this seems the obvious mechanism to use for the control we seek. The overall structure of the tax take must clearly be such as to achieve the steady state, the control action needs to be such that it affects primarily the tax liabilities of those with a low propensity to save but nevertheless subject to tax. This means, using the income tax formula proposed (see previous post, below), the changes should be to both the parameter C which affects mainly the lower incomes, reducing it slightly to increase the tax, and possibly also parameter A.

 

Changes to other types of tax, such as that on companies, are not relevant to this type of control because they do not directly change the amount of money being used to buy goods and services.

 

4. Borrowing

In order to balance the national budget, an alternative to raising taxes is to borrow (or repay loans as an alternative to lowering taxes). Governments borrow money by issuing bonds for sale, and repay loans by redeeming previously issued bonds. However, bonds are almost all bought by financial institutions and even those few which are bought by private citizens are purchased using savings rather than at the expense of buying consumer goods and services, so while borrowing is relevant to the government’s overall need to balance income and expenditure, it is completely irrelevant to the control mechanism being discussed here.

 

Implementation

A considerable amount of carefully directed research will be needed in each country before attempting to use this system in order to determine what balance of the various controls mentioned is most appropriate and what magnitude of change is required to produce what magnitude of effect, and how quickly. This research must be both practical by measuring all relevant factors but also theoretical, using advanced control system theory. Furthermore, this research will have to be ongoing once the system is in place and working, partly to monitor its effectiveness and partly so as to make any necessary modifications to take account of changed conditions, such as in international markets, social changes, new inventions, natural disasters and so on. This is not just a feedback control system, but an adaptive system, changing its control parameters to meet changing conditions. This is most certainly not an area for the exercise of political prejudice by government of whatever colour!

Income Tax Formula

  1. Introduction

    This post is concerned purely with the mechanics of deriving the rate of income tax to be applied, and not with any discussion of the relative merits of income tax as compared with other forms of tax.

    The purpose of this post is to explore ways in which income tax rates can be derived by algebraic formulae to avoid the discontinuities and other ill-effects associated with the more usual system of tax bands. Various formulae are derived and typical results of their use are shown in graphical form. One particular formula is then selected for recommended use, and is described in the main tax discussion. I show comparisons with the existing (at the time of writing) UK tax system, not because it is typical but because it is the only one with which I am familiar and it is almost certainly as complex as any.

  2. The UK system

    Income tax consists of several separate elements in UK, only one of which actually carries that name! The others are some of the different classes of so-called National Insurance Contributions (NIC), which earn entitlements to various state benefits such as unemployment pay and pensions. The income-related classes, with which we are concerned here, are levied on employees, their employers and self-employed people. The employers’ payments affect the employee only indirectly, since they increase the cost of employing him/her, and I shall ignore them in this discussion for simplicity. Since the self-employed payments are quite different from those for employees, I shall also ignore them here. I shall, therefore, compare with my alternative formulae the result of applying the existing (at the time of writing) UK income tax plus employees’ National Insurance Contributions. I shall also ignore the complexities of different rates being applied to certain kinds of unearned income such as interest and dividends.

    The UK income tax system (as at 2006), after deducting allowances dependent on personal circumstances, applied three different rates of tax to different bands of income, 10% on the first £2,150 earned, then 22% on the next £31,150 and 40% on the remainder.

    The employee’s NIC were 0% on the first £5,035, 11% on the next £28,505 and 1% on the remainder. This is a simplified explanation, but is adequate for our purpose here.

  3. Requirements

    We require a system which applies a progressive system of tax rates and can be easily adjusted both in terms of the total tax revenue to be achieved from it and the degree to which it is progressive. It is also obviously necessary that the rate should never exceed 100%, and the formula should be capable of having set a minimum income level below which no tax should be levied. In a genuinely progressive system not only should the total tax levied increase as income increases, but so should the marginal rate.

  4. Derivation of the formula

    I looked for a formula for which both the marginal and total tax rates started low and increased asymptotically towards a maximum. Starting with the marginal rate, I came up with:

    `

    r = A(1-C.exp(1-i/B))

    `

    `````````````
    where:``
    r =` marginal tax rate`
    i =` income`

    A, B and C are parameters available to make adjustments.

    `

    From this the corresponding formula for the total tax can be obtained by integration:

    `Equation for tax rate

    `

    `````````````
    where:``
    T =` total tax rate`
    i =` income`

    and K is a constant chosen to make T = 0 when i = B
    Hence K = A.B + A.B.C

  5. Application of the formula

    The first point to note in using the formula is that the parameters A, B and C have specific, easily understood functions. A is the maximum tax rate to be applied to the highest incomes (marginal and total rates). B is the level of income at which tax is to be applied. C is an adjustment used to determine the overall level of tax, and hence the total revenue to be raised, without changing the other two parameters. A purely hypothetical example is used in figure 1 to illustrate the use of the parameter C, where the maximum rate of tax has been set at the high level of 90% and the lowest income to suffer tax is £5,000. The graph for the 2006 UK system is also shown for comparison.

    Image
    Figure 1

    A better comparison with the 2006 UK system is shown in Figure 2, where the maximum rate is 41% (the same as in the UK system) and with C set to 0.60 to give a comparable total tax revenue. [The UK incomes have been increased here by £5,000 so as to correspond with this as a starting level – published figures for UK rates are based on taxable income, after deducting the zero-tax amount.]

    Image
    Figure 2

    Figure 3 below shows up very clearly the illogical nature of the UK system in its effect on marginal tax rates, with not only the various steps but also the serious anomaly between £38,310 and £38,350 where the marginal rate rises to 51% before falling back to 41%.

    Image
    Figure 3

  6. Conclusion

    The income tax payable by an individual (the only tax based on income) should be calculated from the formula:

    T = A.i + A.B.C.exp(1-i/B) – A.B – A.B.C

    `

    where:
    T = total tax payable
    i = total income (before deducting tax free allowances)
    A = maximum tax rate payable on the highest incomes
    B = tax free allowance (which can vary between individuals)
    C = a fraction in the region of 0.6.

    The total revenue can be adjusted by varying any of these last three parameters, but it should be noted that reducing C puts an increased burden on the lowest earners (and C = 0 corresponds to a flat rate tax), while increasing A increases the tax burden on all tax payers while remaining highly progressive and is therefore in general preferable. The formula proposed avoids all the anomalies resulting from fixed tax bands and multiple taxes based on income, while remaining highly flexible in all significant ways.

“Carbon” emissions

I do wish people would stop talking about “carbon emissions” when they mean “carbon dioxide emissions”. Carbon is not a greenhouse gas. It is a solid, usually black, and harmless except in a relatively minor way when emitted as black smoke. Carbon dioxide is not even mainly carbon – by weight it is more than twice as much oxygen as carbon, so it would make (very slightly) more sense to talk about “oxygen emissions”!